The term "bioregionalism" was first popularized in the 1970s by ecologist Raymond Dasmann and social
activist Peter Berg. Berg defines a bioregion as ". . . a geographic area defined by natural characteristics including watersheds,
landforms, soils, geological qualities, native plants and animals, climate, and weather." Bioregionalism, Berg suggests, ".
. . promotes an inhabitory attitude by which humans adapt themselves to the natural characteristics of a bioregion in an appropriate
way (Evanoff 1998, 1). Contrary to current trends towards a global economy, in which both resources and goods are freely traded
around the globe, bioregionalism emphasizes relative economic self-reliance based on the principle of local production for
local consumption. Dasmann (1976, 413ff.) used the term "ecosystem people" to describe cultures that are able to live comfortably
and sustainably within local environmental conditions. The term "biosphere people," by contrast, describes cultures which
exploit resources from other environments in order to support a higher standard of living than they could maintain otherwise.
While ecosystem cultures have been the norm throughout most human history, current trends towards globalization encourage
people, particularly in developed countries, to become biosphere people, i.e., to consume more resources than their local
bioregions can sustainably provide. Bioregionalism is not opposed to all forms of trade nor to remedial aid in times of
genuine distress (such as famine). It does suggest, however, that the goal of development assistance should not be to draw
a given region into the global economy but rather to enhance local self-reliance. Dasmann suggests that self-reliance ". .
. involves development of the capacity to supply the basic needs of people-food, energy, water, clothing, shelter. . . ."
(1981, 10). People should be encouraged to grow crops not for export but for their own consumption; manufacturing should similarly
be geared not towards export but towards meeting local needs. Once basic needs have been met, surpluses can be traded. The
principle of local production for local consumption fosters local control over the economic and political decision-making
processes. In a global economy decisions are increasingly made by centralized economic and political institutions which show
little concern for the consequences of their actions on local communities. Transnational corporations by definition do not
belong to any country and ultimately there is no effective democratic means of controlling their activities. International
development and trade institutions, such as the World Bank, the IMF, and World Trade Organization, reflect the interests of
global capital more than they do the interests of local communities. Both wealth and power are increasingly concentrated in
the hands of a global capitalist elite, often at the expense of average citizens in both the developed and developing countries.
A study by the U.S. Chamber of Commerce predicted that by the year 2000 a few hundred transnational corporations will control
more than 50% of the world's total assets (cited in Rifkin 1991, 294). The world's ten largest multinationals make more money
annually than the 100 poorest countries ("Globalization-The Facts," 18). The 400 richest people in the United States have
incomes that are more than the combined gross national products of India, Bangladesh, Sri Lanka, and Nepal-where one billion
people live (Korten 1995, 108). Bioregionalism offers a radical, but non-Marxist, alternative to capitalist-style development.
Bioregionalism is as opposed to the centralization of political power in government bureaucracies as it is to the centralization
of economic power in multinational corporations (cf. Sale 1991). Although bioregionalism respects cultural diversity and seeks
to avoid the creation of what Berg (1981) calls a "global monoculture," it is by no means insular or racist. Bioregionalists
advocate not only the creation of decentralized political and economic structures that are democratically controlled by local
communities, but also the need to build an international grassroots movement that links people together across racial, cultural,
and national lines. The international dimension of bioregionalism, however, has remained undertheorized and it is proposed
here that any bioregional approach to cross-cultural dialogue on global ethics should be based on the following principles:
(1) A concern for meeting basic human needs on a universal basis. A high quality of life should not be equated, however, with
consumerism or overconsumptive lifestyles. (2) A concern for social justice. Social justice does not necessarily mean achieving
complete equality but it should minimally involve avoiding any form of exploitation which allows some individuals in the global
arena to benefit at the expense of others. (3) A concern for ecological integrity. The concept of integrity includes both
the idea that natural resources should be conserved for human use and the idea that sufficient natural habitats should be
preserved to allow the continued evolution of non-human species. This paper argues that modern capitalist-style development
is unable to satisfy any of these three principles. A growing critique is being mounted against "free trade" and the global
economy on the grounds that it increases rather than decreases the gap between rich and poor, undermines democratic decision-making
processes, and is environmentally irresponsible (see, for example, Nader et al. 1993; Lang and Hines 1993; Goldsmith et al.
1995; Mander and Goldsmith 1996; Ekins 1997; Greider 1997). Capitalist development models are based on a unilinear view of
cultural development (cf. Rostow 1960, Kerr et al. 1964) which assumes that developing countries should eventually "catch
up" with the developed countries in terms of material affluence. This view contends that people should give up their traditional
cultures and "modernize," taking developed countries such as the United States and Japan as their models. It further assumes,
in a spirit reminiscent of old imperialist conceits, that since developed countries are "rich" and technologically "superior,"
they have a moral obligation to "help" countries which are "poor" and technologically "backward." The globalization of the
economy represents a form of cultural imperialism on a global scale. Whereas the older forms of imperialism attempted to impose
Western values on non-Westerners, the newer form attempts to impose first-world values on "non-first-worlders." At least two
objections can be made to the catch-up model of development. First, the notion that the developing countries can eventually
"catch up" with the developed countries is a biophysical impossibility. The catch-up model erroneously assumes that the earth
has sufficient resources to support a growing population at standards of living that now prevail in the developed countries.
The dominant value of industrial civilization is that economic growth is a good thing and that increased levels of consumption
lead to greater human well-being. The success of the economy is accordingly measured by how rapidly the production of goods
and services can be expanded. The bioregional paradigm questions the assumption that continued economic growth is possible,
given the fact that the earth has both limited natural resources and limited sinks to absorb the pollution generated by industrial
processes. Calculations show that at least 2-4 planets would be needed to support the earth's present population at levels
of consumption currently found in the developed world (Wackernagel and Rees 1996, 15). Ecological economists contend that
since current rates of economic growth are clearly unsustainable over the long-term, it is impossible for everyone in the
world to enjoy ever-rising levels of material affluence. We cannot, moreover, rely on "technological advances" to save us.
In the 1972 book The Limits to Growth (Meadows et al. 1972) researchers from the Massachusetts Institute of Technology demonstrated
through computer simulations that even if we could double the present energy supply, recycle 75% of other resources, reduce
pollution to one-fourth its present level, double agricultural production, and make effective means of birth control universally
available, economic collapse within the next century could not be avoided. An update of The Limits to Growth published in
1992 (Meadows et al. 1992) largely confirmed the results of the earlier study but argued that present levels of economic growth
have already pushed us "beyond the limits" of ecological sustainability. Together with The Limits to Growth, the bioregional
paradigm suggests that global collapse can be avoided only if concerted efforts are made to give up the pursuit of economic
growth and the "catch-up" model of development. Bioregionalism is by no means opposed to technological innovation, nor does
it advocate a return to Neanderthal lifestyles. It simply argues that economic production should be brought now within the
parameters of sustainability made available by existing technology rather than placing faith in the ability of technological
advances that do not yet even exist to save us from ecological collapse. The goals of bioregionalism are consistent with
those set forth by the economist Herman E. Daly (1991, 1996), who argues that we need to move towards a "steady-state" economy
in which resources are not used up faster than they can be replenished and pollution is not generated more rapidly than the
earth can absorb it. A steady-state economy would discourage people from indulging in luxurious, overconsumptive lifestyles
and focus instead on providing for the basic material needs of all on a more or less equitable basis. While affluent people
in the world would be asked to give up unnecessary consumption, a steady-state economy would insure that everyone on the planet
had access to adequate housing, food, health care, and education-things which many of the world's poor do not enjoy even in
today's high-growth economy. The second objection to the modern development paradigm is that it is simply not working.
Despite the fact that development assistance has increased from $1.8 billion per year in the early 1950s to more than $60
billion per year at present (Hancock 1989, 43 and 187), the gap between rich and poor is actually growing. In 1960 the richest
20% of the world's population had 30 times more wealth than the poorest 20%; in 1994 the figure was 78 times more ("Some sobering
facts and figures" 1997). Bioregional critics of development point out that development projects are often the cause of, rather
than the solution to, poverty. Many case studies could be cited in support of this claim (see, for example, Chatterjee 1994;
Greer and Bruno 1996). The creation of a "global market" based on "free trade" ultimately serves the interests of first-
and third-world elites more than it does the interests of non-elites. Multinational corporations frequently close down factories
in developed countries and reopen them in developing countries to take advantage of low taxes, lax environmental regulations,
and cheap labor. Corporate profits skyrocket at the same time that thousands of first-world workers lose their jobs and tax
revenues for social services are cut. While business elites in the third world also profit from such ventures, third-world
workers are often forced to endure working conditions similar to those described in the novels of Charles Dickens. The combination
of exploitive working conditions and global "free trade" policies leads to competitive pressure which also drives down wages
and benefits in first-world countries. Workers in both the North and the South are engaged in what has been described as a
"race to the bottom" (Brecher and Costello 1994; Korten 1995). In the context of a global market economy, goods are produced
not for those who need them but rather for those who have the money to buy them. The poor, of course, often do not have enough
money to buy even essential goods. At present the richest fifth of the world's population receives approximately 82.7% of
the world's wealth while the poorest fifth receives only 1.4% (Reid 1995, 7). Much of the discrepancy can be blamed on increased
globalization. The economies of many developing countries now depend on exporting natural resources, agricultural products,
and manufactured goods to developed countries. In other words, the poor are not extracting resources, growing food, or making
products for themselves, but rather for the benefit of people in developed countries. In export-driven economies imbalances
are created in which the siphoning off of labor and goods from developing countries to developed countries leaves the poor
with insufficient resources to meet their own basic needs. It is not difficult to see why developed countries, which make
up only about one-fourth of the earth's population, consume about three-fourths of the earth's resources at a rate per capita
that is 15 times that of most people living in the developing countries (Trainer 1985, 3). The poor in developing countries
are increasingly rejecting the idea that their resources and labor should be used to subsidize the overconsumptive lifestyles
of affluent individuals in both the North and South. Alternative development paradigms consistent with bioregional principles
(see, for example, Dag Hammarskjöld Institute 1975; Galtung 1980; Trainer 1989; Max-Neef 1991; Dube 1988; Rahman 1993; Burkey
1993) suggest that citizens in both developed and developing countries should use their resources, agricultural productivity,
and labor to meet basic human needs at the local level. Communities can "delink" themselves from the global economy (Amin
1990) by achieving greater economic self-sufficiency and greater political autonomy. By refusing to ship resources and wealth
to developed countries, the poor would be able to provide for their own basic human needs in a socially just and environmentally
sustainable manner. In the North, meanwhile, there have been increasing calls for developed countries to engage in a process
of "de-development" (Trainer 1985). As early as 1972 A Blueprint for Survival (Goldsmith et al. 1972) suggested that affluent
Northern societies should limit both economic and population growth and try instead to create decentralized communities based
on the concept of self-sufficiency. Similar views have been advanced by Green Party activists (Porritt 1984; Bahro 1984, 1986;
1994) and advocates of deindustrialization (Goldsmith 1988; Kassiola 1990; McLaughlin 1993). In the bioregional model,
levels of wealth could rise slightly in developing countries-i.e., to levels sufficient to meet basic needs-while levels of
wealth in the developed countries would fall since they would no longer be able to exploit the labor or resources of developing
countries. Ted Trainer suggests that the overaffluent should reduce their per capita resource consumption at least 80% so
that everyone can share the earth's resources in an equitable and sustainable way (1985, 248-249). The result would be a rough
parity between North and South at levels of material affluence that both meet basic human needs and are ecologically sustainable.
In the words of a popular slogan, the rich must learn to live more simply so the poor can simply live. The capitalist
development paradigm permits a minority of the world's people to enjoy wealth and luxury, but only by forcing others into
dehumanizing poverty, creating unjust inequalities between rich and poor, and destroying the environment. The capitalist development
paradigm therefore fails to satisfy any of the three ethical principles presented earlier in this paper. A bioregional approach,
to the contrary, would satisfy these principles. There is no doubt that asking developed countries to drastically reduce overconsumption
and developing countries to curb their aspirations for development will not be popular, but the bioregional paradigm is hardly
utopian. It is based on an eminently realistic assessment of how basic human needs can be globally satisfied in a socially
just and ecologically responsible way. Rather, it is the capitalist development paradigm with its unfulfillable promise that
everyone on the planet can duplicate the overconsumptive lifestyles of the affluent North which is utopian and unrealistic.
Acknowledgements Sections of this paper have been adapted from chapters contributed to the textbook, Make It or
Break It: The Future of Our Environment. Tokyo: Sanshusha, 1999.
References Amin, Samir (1990). Delinking: Towards
a Polycentric World. Trans. Michael Wolfers. London: Zed Books. Bahro, Rudolf (1984). From Red to Green. Trans. Gus Fagan
and Richard Hurst. London: Verso. --- (1986). Building the Green Movement. Trans. Mary Tyler. London: Heretic. ---
(1994). Avoiding Social and Ecological Disaster: The Politics of World Transformation. Bath: Gateway Books. Berg, Peter
(1981). "Devolving Beyond Global Monoculture." CoEvolutionary Quarterly 32:24-30. Brecher, Jeremy and Tim Costello (1994).
Global Village or Global Pillage? Economic Reconstruction from the Bottom Up. Boston: South End Press. Burkey, Stan (1993).
People First: A Guide to Self-Reliant Participatory Rural Development. London: Zed Books. Chatterjee, Pratap (1994). 50
Years is Enough! 50 Years of World Bank Development Projects. London: Friends of the Earth. Dag Hammarskjöld Institute
(1975). What Now? Another Development. Uppsala: Dag Hammarskjöld Institute. Daly, Herman E. (1991). Steady-State Economics.
2nd ed. Washington, D.C.: Island Press. --- (1996). Beyond Growth: The Economics of Sustainable Development. Boston: Beacon
Press. Dasmann, Raymond F. (1976). Environmental Conservation. 4th ed. New York: John Wiley and Sons. --- (1981).
"Eco-Development: Decolonizing Ourselves." Raise the Stakes! 1(2):10-11. Dube, S. C. (1988). Modernization and Development:
The Search for Alternative Paradigms. Tokyo: United Nations University. Ekins, Paul (1997). "The Future of the World Trade
Organization: Proposals for Fair and Environmentally Sustainable Trade." Democracy and Nature 3:57-89. Evanoff, Richard
(1998). "Bioregionalism Comes to Japan: An Interview with Peter Berg." Japan Environment Monitor, in press. Galtung, Johan
(1980). "Self-Reliance: Concepts, Practice and Rationale." In J. Galtung, P. O'Brien, and R. Preiswerk, eds. Self-Reliance.
London: L'Ouverture Publications for the Institute of Development Studies. "Globalization-The Facts" (1997). New Internationalist
296:18-19. Goldsmith, Edward (1988). The Great U-Turn: Deindustrializing Society. Bideford: Green Books. Goldsmith,
Edward, Robert Allen, Michael Allaby, John Davoll, and Sam Lawrence (1972). A Blueprint for Survival. Middlesex: Penguin.
Goldsmith, Edward, Martin Khor, Helena Norberg-Hodge, Vandana Shiva, et al. (1995). The Future of Progress: Reflections
on Environment and Development. Totnes: Resurgence. Greer, Jed and Kelly Bruno (1996). Greenwash: The Reality Behind Corporate
Environmentalism. Penang: Third World Network, 1996. Greider, William (1997). One World, Ready or Not: The Manic Logic
of Global Capitalism. New York: Simon and Schuster. Hancock, Graham (1989). Lords of Poverty: The Power, Prestige and
Corruption of the International Aid Business. New York: Atlantic Monthly Press. Kassiola, Joel Jay (1990). The Death of
Industrial Civilization. Albany: State University of New York Press. Kerr, Charles, John T. Dunlop, Frederick H. Harbison,
and Charles A. Meyers (1964). Industrialism and Industrial Man. Middlesex: Penguin. Korten, David (1995). When Corporations
Rule the World. London: Earthscan. Lang, Tim and Colin Hines (1993). The New Protectionism: Protecting the Future Against
Free Trade. London: Earthscan. Mander, Jerry and Edward Goldsmith (1996). The Case Against the Global Economy: And For
a Turn to the Local. San Francisco: Sierra Club Books. Max-Neef, Manfred (1991). Human-Scale Development: Concepts, Applications
and Further Reflections. New York: Apex Press. McLaughlin, Andrew (1993). Regarding Nature: Industrialism and Deep Ecology.
Albany: State University of New York Press. Meadows, Donella H., Dennis L. Meadows, Jørgen Randers, and Ill Behrens (1972).
The Limits to Growth. New York: Universe Books. Meadows, Donella H., Dennis L. Meadows, and Jørgen Randers (1992). Beyond
the Limits: Global Collapse or a Sustainable Future. Post Mills: Chelsea Green. Nader, Ralph, William Greider, Margaret
Atwood, Vandana Shiva, Mark Ritchie, Wendell Berry, Jerry Brown, Herman Daly, Lori Wallach, Thea Lee, Martin Khor, David Phillips,
Jorge Castañeda, Carlos Heredia, David Morris, and Jerry Mander (1993). The Case Against "Free Trade": GATT, NAFTA, and the
Globalization of Corporate Power. San Francisco: Earth Island Press. Pepper, David (1996). Modern Environmentalism: An
Introduction. London: Routledge. Porritt, Jonathon (1984). Seeing Green: The Politics of Ecology Explained. Oxford: Basil
Blackwell. Rahman, Md Anisur (1993). People's Self-Development: Perspectives on Participatory Action Research. Dhaka:
University Press. Reid, David (1995). Sustainable Development: An Introductory Guide. London: Earthscan. Rifkin, Jeremy
(1991). Biosphere Politics. New York: Crown Publishers. Rostow, W. W. (1960). The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist
Manifesto. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Sale, Kirkpatrick (1991). Dwellers in the Land: The Bioregional Vision.
Philadelphia: New Society. "Some sobering facts and figures" (1997). International Society for Environmental Ethics Newsletter
8(Fall): 6. Trainer, F. E. (1985). Abandon Affluence! Sustainable Development and Social Change. London: Zed Books. ---
(1989). Developed to Death. London: Merlin Press. Wackernagel, Mathis and William Rees (1996). Our Ecological Footprint:
Reducing Human Impact on the Earth. Philadephia: New Society. World Commission on Environment and Development (1987).
Our Common Future. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
|